The euro was worth 6.94 birr in October 2000, and then peaked in April 2014 at 27 birr before falling to 21.93 in March 2015.During the fifteen-year period economic fundamentals were as follows:
Early 2000, Ethiopia’s external debt was unsustainable. Debt forgiveness/rescheduling in 2000-2008 and 2010 – plus substantial external aid – have brought indebtedness to a manageable level. In 2014, the debt to GDP ratio was a healthy 22.6% (est.), but is now increasing due to public sector investment expenditure. External debt as a percentage of exports and primary income looks less healthy as export performance remains unsatisfactory.
If the inflation differential between Ethiopia and Euro zone turns out 8.5% in 2015, then the exchange rate recorded in Q1-2015 means a 25% real exchange rate appreciation of the BIRR against the Euro compared to 2014. Unrealistic, considering Ethiopia’s CA deficit – even when corrected for FDI inflows – while the Euro zone CA may top €200 billion surplus in 2015. Finally, the forex reserves exceeded 3-month worth of imports in 2002-03; reserves are currently about 2 months only. Foreign currency shortage is a recurrent problem in Ethiopia explaining the existence of a parallel market and rationing of foreign exchange. Of course, the issue of devaluation is sensitive because devaluation produces winners and losers. But, what devaluation seeks to achieve is a change in the relative price of exportable goods (vis-à-vis non-tradables) resulting hopefully in a boost of export performance, and, a disincentive to imports (thus a strategy of efficient import substitution).
EXCHANGE RATE REGIMES
The choice of an exchange rate regime is important for competitiveness, macroeconomic stability and growth. Exchange Rate regimes are classified as fixed exchange rate, fully floating market-determined exchange rate or intermediate regimes. Ethiopian authorities describe their Exchange Rate regime as a managed float (= intermediate regime) with no predetermined path for the exchange rate.
Before an auction system was established in 1992/93, the BIRR was pegged to the USD at 2.07 BIRR. An inter-bank foreign exchange
market was created in October 2001 with the National Bank of Ethiopia intervening.
Historically, depreciation pressures on the BIRR have prevailed. While the USD-BIRR rate stands around 20.5 in May 2015, the IMF (Oct. 2014) estimated the Real Effective Exchange Rate overvaluation in the range of 10-13%. The “authorities acknowledge that a competitive exchange rate is important but consider too rapid adjustment to be counterproductive due to feedback effects on inflation”.
Under Ethiopia’s regime:
- Ethiopians and Residents of Ethiopia surrender, through a forex bureau, all foreign currencies in their possession against payment in BIRR.
- Exporters are allowed to maintain a retention account to hold a specified amount of their export earnings for a defined period, with the remainder being surrendered by local banks to NBE. The percentage of authorized retention has fluctuated over time (and is determined by Directive; the rate was 10% (Directive 11/1998).
- The NBE determines terms and conditions for transfer of foreign exchange and the exports or imports of goods (import permits).
MONETARY POLICY
The NBE aims to maintain sufficient international reserves to cover (a) payments for immediate and short term imports of commodities and services into Ethiopia, (b) foreign debt payment commitments. When reserves decline, the Governor considers remedial measures and may suspend issuance of foreign exchange permits.
The bank carries out monetary management with a mix of policy instruments: sale/ purchase of securities issued by Government, a central bank credit facility to cover commercial banks’ short-term need, reserve requirements, setting floor deposit interest rate, use of credit control and moral suasion.
The Monetary Policy Committee of the NBE reviews quarterly the economic developments and proposes a monetary policy stance to the
Board of Directors in line with targets for inflation, growth rates of monetary aggregates, GDP growth rate, the real equilibrium exchange rate and the foreign exchange reserve.
The NBE is the biggest generator of foreign currency and enables it to intervene as the major market player, assuring exchange rate stability to some degree.
The dilemma of any policy decision maker is to achieve x targets with y instruments. If the number of targets exceeds the number of instruments available, then meeting the targets would be a matter of pure coincidence. Even if the number of Central Bank’s policy instruments exceeds the number of targets, it is not certain that the CB will be able to meet trend targets as it has limited or no influence on productivity growth, investments and external demand. Therefore, it may miss one or several targets. The question is which ones shall be sacrificed?
IMPACT OF DEVALUATION
Economists focusing on economic fundamentals as drivers of exchange rate movements look at:
- Price inflation differentials;
- Current Account: surpluses (deficits) cause currency appreciation (depreciation). The long-run equilibrium exchange rate comes with a sustained balanced Current Account.
- Differentials in domestic/foreign money demand and nominal interest rate, between countries;
- Stock of foreign debt relative to GNP (or to Exports). A high ratio is considered a risk. Potential investors require a risk premium above the normal nominal interest rates in order to make up for the expected future depreciation necessary to rebalance the Current Account deficit.
Pressure for devaluation comes from a deterioration of domestic competitiveness due to domestic inflation being higher than inflation in competitor countries, from the existence of unsustainable Current Account deficits and increase in foreign debt (affecting the creditworthiness), or other reasons (e.g. the structure of foreign debt).
Speculative attacks do occur resulting in ER movements not in line with fundamentals.
From the observation of two experiences with devaluation (Franc CFA in 1994 and 1997 Asian financial crises) we have learnt that:
- After devaluation, the Balance of Trade significantly improved in 8 countries out of 14. It worked for the Asian economies.
- Export volumes improved, after devaluation, in 7 out of 9 CFA countries. By contrast, export performance deteriorated in all Asian economies, although the performance was still solid.
- Growth in Import volumes actually increased in the 10 years following devaluation in 7 out of 9 CFA countries 9 studied. In all Asian countries imports growth fell, as a result of lower domestic demand, explaining why currency devaluation in the Asian economies improved the Balance of Trade.
- GDP growth visibly improved in all but one of the CFA countries, constituting a turnaround from negative growth experienced before devaluation. By contrast, GDP growth in Indonesia, Korea, Thailand and Malaysia fell significantly from previous solid growth, though resuming in year-2.
- The Investment rate (as % of GDP) improved in all but one of CFA countries studied. Thus, devaluation is compatible with resource mobilization and GDP growth. By contrast, the investment rate fell in all five Asian economies studied, coming down from very high – unsustainable – rates in Korea, Thailand and Malaysia.
Post-devaluation inflation is often used as an argument AGAINST. In Indonesia and Thailand, devaluation triggered double-digit inflation for 2 years. However, fears for sustained inflation were exaggerated; the dynamics of the price spiral is not known beforehand but depends on country-specific circumstances. It is also
true that domestic price increase erodes the initial positive impact on price competitiveness, but this is a process takes up to ten years in most cases.
The difficulty of CFA economies to maintain high economic growth under conditions of sustainability, following currency devaluation, is linked to a structural issue. For an economy to be able to increase export supply and to substitute for imports, its industry must be sufficiently diversified. One expects the supply response to be stronger the larger the manufacturing base of the economy. This was the case in Asia. Ethiopia’s economy is notoriously undiversified.
In conclusion, currency realignment can work. If the objective behind a devaluation strategy is to restore price competitiveness, then the devaluation basically BUYS YOU TIME to develop intrinsic competitiveness in your tradables sectors. Competitiveness requires business upgrading to boost productivity, product/services innovation and market diversification. These are processes which cannot be changed overnight.